Wednesday, June 22, 2011

The Rise Of China's [PRC] Economy

From FPRI:

Foreign Policy Research Institute


Over 50 Years of Ideas in Service to Our Nation

www.fpri.org



Footnotes

The Newsletter of FPRI's Wachman Center



THE RISE OF CHINA'S ECONOMY

by Thomas G. Rawski



Vol. 16, No. 6

June 2011



Thomas G. Rawski, Professor of Economics and History, joined

the University of Pittsburgh's faculty in 1985 after

fourteen years at the University of Toronto. His research

focuses on the nature and implications of recent

developments and long-term changes in the economy of China.

He delivered this paper at A History Institute for Teachers,

March 19-20, 2011 on "China and India: Ancient

Civilizations, Rising Powers, Giant Societies, and

Contrasting Models of Development," held at the University

of Pennsylvania. This History Institute was co-sponsored by

The Foreign Policy Research Institute's Wachman Center as

well as by three centers at the University of Pennsylvania -

Center for East Asian Studies, South Asia Center, and Penn

Lauder CIBER (Center for International Business Education

and Research). [1]



Available on the web and in pdf format at:

http://www.fpri.org/footnotes/1606.201106.rawski.chineseeconomy.html



THE RISE OF CHINA'S ECONOMY



by Thomas G. Rawski



China's remarkable economic boom, now in its fourth decade,

has spawned numerous discussions of "China's Rise."[2]

Beijing's self-congratulatory slogan "China's peaceful rise"

has advanced this theme. From a historical perspective,

however, this terminology seems misplaced. Both the Ming

(1368-1644) and Qing (1644-1912) empires occupied key

positions in Asian trade and diplomacy. Crude figures

compiled by Angus Maddison, author of several sweeping

studies of global economic history, show China contributing

nearly one-third of global output as late as 1820. The great

boom of the late twentieth century has enabled China to

regain some of the global economic weight and leverage that

the Middle Kingdom enjoyed during the Ming and much of the

Qing eras.



The industrial revolution pushed European and North American

productivity far ahead of China and India, former giants

whose combined share of global output plunged from nearly

half to under one-tenth between 1820 and 1950.[3] Prior to

1800, Europeans-for example Marco Polo[4]-viewed China as

prosperous and well-governed. As China's relative economic

position eroded, opinions shifted. Both Europeans and

Chinese came to view China as a backward society whose very

foundations-families, beliefs, values-obstructed progress.

Hu Shi (1891-1962), a prominent philosopher who served as

China's wartime ambassador to the United States, summarized

this perspective in Chabuduo xiansheng (?????), a witty

vignette portraying Chinese people as incapable of the

precise thinking needed in the modern world.[5]



China's recent economic boom, along with the success of Hong

Kong, Taiwan, and Singapore, demonstrates that Chinese

culture is not inimical to economic progress. Indeed, the

opposite perspective, which sees Chinese society as

unusually capable of producing individuals who can operate

effectively in market systems, helps to explain China's

historic prominence as well as its recent economic surge.



Early work by the late G.W. Skinner (1925-2008), a brilliant

and innovative Sinological anthropologist, highlights the

economic capabilities of ordinary Chinese before and during

the heyday of European imperial expansion. Chinese

migrants, many of whom "came to Siam almost straight from

the farm," dominated Thailand's domestic and international

commerce. Skinner explains this in terms of cultural

contrasts. In the "Thai universe," shaped by the ecology of

"an underpopulated and fertile land where the requirements

for subsistence were [_] easily obtained. [_] thrift as such

was of limited value, and work for its own sake simply

senseless." The migrants hailed from a different universe:

"the south Chinese peasant lived in a grimly Malthusian

setting where thrift and industry were essential for

survival." Ideology reinforced this divergence: Chinese

struggled for wealth to preserve family and lineage

continuity, while Thai norms frowned on "excessive concern

for _ material advancement." Differences in proverbs tell

the story: for the Chinese, "Money can do all things," but

for the Thai, "Do not long for more than your own share."

[6]



Recognizing the strength of entrenched Chinese interests,

the British forced the Thai monarch to grant them "equal

commercial rights as well as additional privileges" in 1855,

benefits that soon extended to "all the major trading states

of Europe and America." In 1890, "after thirty-five years of

Western free-trading_ under privileged conditions," Chinese

merchants still controlled nearly two-thirds of Bangkok's

trade, more than double that engrossed by the British. In

Siam, as in China and Japan, the domestic business of

European and American firms was invariably managed by "a

Chinese merchant of some wealth, Western training, and

standing in the Chinese community." Chinese dominance

extended even to the rice trade, "the biggest prize of all

in Siam," where "the pioneering Western mills were abandoned

or passed into Chinese hands."[7]



Chinese economic capabilities originated in Chinese village

life. The Ming-Qing era witnessed a rapid expansion of

commerce. Rural households attended periodic markets to

buy, sell, or barter farm produce, labor services, animals,

fodder, handicraft materials and products, household

necessities, and loans, sometimes on a daily basis.[8] The

reliance of these markets on a complex monetary system that

used copper cash for small purchases and silver coin,

ingots, and bullion to manage tax payments and wholesale

transactions injected the variable exchange rate between

copper and silver into the economic lives of all Chinese.

Rural markets were highly competitive: poor but energetic

individuals could enter the commercial world as middlemen,

earning commissions facilitating local transactions.



Written documents occupied an important position in economic

life. Arrangements for short- and long-term labor services,

for renting, mortgaging or transferring land, for selling,

storing, or conveying merchandise, and for marriage,

adoption, apprenticeship, and division of family property

routinely involved written contracts. The operation of

kinship groups, mercantile and native-place associations,

crop-watching societies and other private organizations

revolved around complex written arrangements. Both men and

women (who often brought their own funds into their

husbands' households) participated in village-level economic

life. Documents also permeated interactions with the state.



These circumstances placed a premium on literacy and

numeracy, even for humble villagers. In late Qing, literacy

extended to 30-45 percent of males and 2-10 percent of

females-high figures when compared with pre-industrial

Europe.[9] Age-heaping, the tendency of illiterates to give

their age in round numbers (so that more people identify

themselves as being 20 years old than 19 or 21), is

prominent in many low-income nations, but notably absent in

nineteenth-century China.[10]



While suffering the low incomes, short life expectancy, and

high infant mortality that afflict poor people everywhere,

Chinese villagers attained disproportionate levels of

entrepreneurial capability, organizational skill and

commercial sophistication that often enabled them to out-

compete natives of other Asian countries and even Europeans,

not just in Shanghai and Bangkok, but across wide swathes of

Asia. Colonial authorities in Batavia, Manila, and

Singapore found the services of Chinese to be

"indispensable."[11] These unusual features did not extend

uniformly across China's landscape, but concentrated in

regions with the most extensive development of trade. These

included the lower reaches of the Yangzi River, which formed

the hub of domestic commerce, as well as the southern

coastal provinces of Fujian and Guangdong, the source of

large-scale overseas migration.[12]



These regional differences persist. Chinese executives

report wide regional variation in manufacturing capability:

"Managers at a leading maker of auto parts were only able to

produce products that were less 'quality demanding' in their

inland facilities. _ [where] efforts to raise standards

encounter broader cultural obstacles."[13] Even though

massive infrastructure growth has reduced economic distances

between inland cities and China's ports, foreign investments

cluster along the coast. Speaking in 2008, Commerce

Minister Chen Deming emphasized the regional imbalance in

commercial expertise, promising to "help set up centers to

train business brains in East China for the central

region."[14]



During the nineteenth century, growing pressure by

expanding European powers, later joined by the United States

and Japan, led to a procession of "unequal treaties" which

compelled China to cede territory and authority to avoid

open warfare with the militarily superior imperial powers.

While the resulting erosion of Chinese sovereignty created a

lasting sense of grievance, the economic consequences of the

"unequal treaties" were broadly beneficial. The free trade

regime imposed under the 1842 Treaty of Nanking lasted

nearly a century. Even though free trade imposed costs

associated with unrestricted imports of opium,[15] Peter

Lindert conjectures that "common folk were among the

greatest gainers" from China's growing exports of labor-

intensive commodities-tea and silk in the nineteenth

century, cotton textiles in the twentieth.[16] Treaty

provisions allowing foreigners to reside, trade, and, after

1895, to operate factories in an expanding roster of open

ports accelerated the inflow of new technologies and

ideas-among them telegraph, steamships, railways, new-style

banks, company law, and advertising-that contributed to

long-term economic modernization.



Despite these supportive circumstances, sustained growth was

slow to arrive. To be sure, the Taiping Rebellion of

1851-1864 inflicted massive damage, turning some prosperous

regions into wastelands. But what of the 40-plus years

between the suppression of the Taipings and the Qing

collapse of 1911? One might expect that the combination of

political stability, open and competitive trade, and a

government moderately supportive of reform would have

kindled substantial economic advance, especially with the

extra momentum that recovery from war often provides. But

available materials do not encourage this line of thinking.

Nor do we have a clear idea of what structures or forces

might have limited economic advance during the final Qing

decades. The list of possible constraining factors includes

the difficulty of building momentum in a large economy and

the state's tiny fiscal resources-each quite different in

Japan, as well as China's lack of readily accessible coal

deposits.[17]



Despite domestic political instability and mounting Japanese

incursions, the decades between China's 1911 revolution and

the outbreak of the Sino-Japanese war in 1937 finally

delivered a marked economic upswing. Manufacturing grew

steeply, albeit from a tiny base, along with components of

the urban economy. These gains spilled into the much larger

farm sector, as urban factory growth raised the demand for

cotton and wheat, expansion of transport networks enlarged

markets for rural products, and banks experimented with

retail farm lending. Rising wages in textiles and coal

mining, occupations that attracted unskilled rural migrants,

and in agriculture itself attest to modest but definite

increases in agricultural productivity and incomes, changes

that affected the majority of China's vast labor force.[18]



The outbreak of war in 1937, followed by a steeply rising

inflationary spiral, imposed a double blow that reversed a

quarter-century of economic advance, but not before new

institutions had demonstrated their strength by cushioning

China's economy against the worst consequences of the global

depression that began in 1929. Although large outflows of

silver, the foundation of China's pre-war currency system,

threatened to tip China's economy into a deflationary

downdraft, China's private bankers, operating without the

benefit of official regulation or support, persuaded their

fellow citizens to increase their reliance on private

banknotes and deposits with the result that the money stock

actually increased during the 1930s. This contributed to the

surprising resiliency of China's economy, and limited the

depth and duration of the decline in prices, wages,

investment, and output, all of which were far smaller than

in many other nations.[19]



PEOPLE'S REPUBLIC OF CHINA ESTABLISHED

Following Japan's surrender and the conclusion of the

ensuing civil war, leaders of the newly established People's

Republic of China faced a poisonous cocktail of runaway

inflation, budget deficits, and widespread reluctance to

hold currency or bank deposits. These difficulties were

quickly resolved despite the added complication of China's

October 1950 entry into the Korean War.



Buoyed by this initial success, China's new leaders

redirected their economic efforts toward growth. Their

actions reflected the widespread mistrust of private

enterprise and international markets common among low-income

nations at the time. China's alliance with the Soviet Union

and confrontation with the U.S. strengthened the tilt toward

planning, public enterprise, and isolation from global

markets. The design of China's economic plans followed

Soviet example (as did India's): concentrate resources in

industries that can ramp up domestic capacity to expand

industrial investment. As in the USSR, raising output of

"machines to produce machines" became the key goal. This

trajectory called for large-scale expansion of steel,

electricity, mining, machine-building, and related

industries, along with a supportive educational and research

infrastructure. Planners viewed higher consumption as a

cost-essential (in small quantities) to preserve

incentives-rather than a policy objective.



The effort to channel resources toward industrialization

posed difficult choices for rural policy. Raising crop

purchase prices could increase farm output and incomes, and

provide new opportunities for resource transfer, but only if

investment in consumer goods and farm equipment sufficed to

maintain farmers' incentives. Alternatively,

collectivization might enlarge the available surplus farm

products without shifting investment away from priority

sectors. Farm policy vacillated between these poles until

1958, when Mao Zedong's personal intervention shifted policy

decisively toward collectivization. Farmland, tools,

livestock, and rural labor were hastily absorbed into large

"People's Communes," amid an intense campaign to raise

output of grain and steel. This "Great Leap Forward"

shattered administrative routines, wasted vast resources,

undermined work incentives, and triggered a man-made famine

that cost 30 million lives. To make matters worse, growing

friction between Beijing and Moscow prompted the USSR to

withdraw its technical support, crippling numerous

industrial projects.



Soon after economic planners managed to restore some

semblance of normal economic functioning, Mao Zedong

intervened again to promote another disruptive political

movement, the "Cultural Revolution," which began in 1966.

Economic costs, although far smaller than during the "Great

Leap," were considerable, especially in education, where

colleges and schools either shut down or abandoned normal

standards for up to ten years.



The death of Mao Zedong in 1976 was widely seen as a turning

point for economic policy. People were not satisfied.

Despite important economic achievements in growth,

industrialization, technology (including nuclear weapons and

space exploration), and human development (rising literacy,

declining infant mortality, control of infectious diseases),

China's socialist system had fallen short in two key

dimensions. The commune system failed to solve China's food

problem: as one local leader put it "hunger suddenly emerged

without warning [in 1959] _ For the next twenty years, the

problem of hunger was part of our lives."[20] Furthermore,

the country lagged far behind the economic achievements of

neighbors whom most Chinese viewed as inferior: defeated

Japan, colonial Hong Kong, Kuomintang-controlled Taiwan.



REFORMS IN THE 1970s

In reviewing the astonishing outcome of the reforms begun

during the late 1970s, it is essential to recall their

modest scope. The initial effort included three components.

Impoverished localities began to experiment with household

farming. Four new Special Economic Zones in the southern

coastal provinces of Guangdong and Fujian exposed a sliver

of China's isolated economy to international trade and

investment. Government-owned urban firms could now retain a

modest share of profits as an incentive to "enliven state

assets"; revived markets for industrial inputs and products

provided an outlet for retained profits.



The agricultural initiatives met with instant success.

Farmers raced to abandon collectives and reinstate household

cultivation. Massive (and completely unexpected) increases

in agricultural production raised farm incomes and improved

the diets, energy and productivity of villagers everywhere.

Rising farm output swelled exports and curtailed food

imports, eliminating long-standing concerns over the

availability of food and foreign exchange supplies. The farm

boom disgorged new supplies of industrial materials (grain,

cotton, sugar, fruit) and revealed vast surpluses of rural

labor. Together with rising rural demand and increased

access to urban markets and expertise, these changes fuelled

an explosive boom in rural industry.



Results of the trade initiatives also dwarfed expectations.

Initial prospects seemed limited because the managers of

China's special zones, unlike their counterparts in Taiwan

or the Philippines, lacked international experience. But the

opening of trade zones coincided with growing pressure from

higher wages and land prices on the cost of labor-intensive

exports originating in Taiwan and Hong Kong. These exporters

began to shift operations to the mainland, where the new

combination of abundant low-cost labor with the knowledge,

skills, and experience of Hong Kong and Taiwanese

entrepreneurs generated an export boom that soon launched

China from self-imposed isolation into the developing

world's largest recipient of foreign investment.



Looking back, it now seems evident that the unexpectedly

large payoff to modest reforms in agriculture and trade owed

much to the legacy of human capital accumulated within China

and among overseas Chinese during the decades and centuries

prior to 1949. While "agricultural projects in East Africa

_ suffer from a shortage of well-trained African accountants

_ [who can manipulate] a simple cost-accounting system,"[21]

Chinese villagers quickly mastered the complex record-

keeping demands of the commune system. Once reform began,

the supply of managers and accountants easily accommodated

massive expansion of township and village enterprises, which

mushroomed to encompass 18.5 million firms with 92.6 million

workers and over $10 billion worth of goods procured for

export in 1990.[22]



Urban reform turned out to be far more complex. Vast swathes

of Chinese manufacturing were creatures of the plan that

lacked any market heritage. Furthermore, urban reform cut to

the core of Chinese socialism, which, despite its rural

background, had long focused its attention on the

development of cities and the welfare of urbanites. Chinese

leaders entered the reform process with vague notions of

improved economic performance rather than clear objectives.

At the same time, entrenched party and bureaucratic

interests eliminated any possibility of sweeping reform.

This turned the transformation of China's urban, industrial

economy into a lengthy process that gave birth to the

distinctive features of Chinese gradual reform.



With "big bang" reforms of the sort attempted in Russia and

Eastern Europe neither feasible nor, in the view of Chinese

leaders, desirable, urban reform evolved as a series of

policy experiments and initiatives, decentralized responses,

and official reactions. At the outset, Deng Xiaoping and

his reform-minded colleagues sought to improve outcomes

rather than to pursue a clear vision for China's post-reform

economy. Because Chinese planning was relatively

decentralized, with provincial and local leaders enjoying

greater authority and control than in the Soviet Union,

central reform initiatives typically focused on enabling

measures that broadened the opportunities and choices

available to enterprises and lower-level governments.

Instead of eliminating price controls, China gradually

raised the share of sales transacted at market prices.

Rather than privatize, a growing range of firms began to

issue shares. Production planning did not vanish, but its

span of control gradually diminished.



This open-ended approach invites decentralized reactions

that the center cannot fully anticipate or control.

Governments at all levels become participants; sometimes

even followers, as well as leaders of reform. Reform unfolds

as a process replete with interactions among governments,

enterprises, workers, and consumers rather than as a

sequence of events in which the state imposes decisions on

businesses and individuals.



UNFORESEEN OUTCOMES

The heterogeneous nature of China's pre-reform system meant

that the effect of Beijing's reform initiatives was far from

uniform. The uneven impact of enabling reforms destabilized

outcomes and intensified competition. Competition reduces

profits. In socialist China, government agencies and state-

owned enterprises, which controlled the bulk of capital

assets, suffered mightily. The steep decline in

government's share of national product during the 1980s

illustrates the importance of unforeseen outcomes. Some

enterprises reacted to financial pressures by developing new

products, trimming costs, and raising productivity. Others

bombarded their official sponsors with claims of "unfair

competition" and pleas for financial assistance.

Supervisory agencies, short of funds because of the slow

growth in their revenues from profits (or taxes on profits),

often found it easier to respond with further reform

initiatives than with cash.



In this way, Chinese reform created a "virtuous cycle" that

enabled myriad small reforms to cumulate into substantial

institutional change. Reform expanded competition and

created financial pressures that spurred some participants

toward innovation, resulting in further intensification of

competition. Even when financial pressures resulted in

lobbying rather than innovation, the typical response

involved further partial reform, which unleashed fresh

rounds of competition.



This system produced an odd structure in which the balance

between plan and market varied widely for different official

agencies, regions, enterprises, and households. Variation

allowed participants to weigh their own prospects under each

system. As Susan Shirk has shown, the result was a gradual

shift of opinion toward preference for market outcomes that

culminated in the China's Communist Party's 1993 decision to

pursue a "socialist market economy with Chinese

characteristics." [23]



Comparison of circumstances in 1993 with the recent past

shows that subsequent development has followed the track

established by the 1993 decision, under which government was

to undertake macroeconomic management, regulation of health,

environment etc., and setting strategic priorities for the

economy, leaving other decisions to the market. The shift

from plan to market continues: the share of industrial

output originating in state-owned or collective firms that

are subject to strong official controls plunged from 81.7 to

11.0 percent between 1993 and 2008. The move from public to

private ownership has accelerated, with the share of

domestic private firms and firms with offshore investment in

industrial production leaping from 18.5 to 56.4 percent

during the same period.[24] Continued movement from

isolation toward global involvement is also clear: between

1993 and 2008, annual two-way trade advanced from $195.7

billion to $2.56 trillion, China's trade ratio (combined

exports and imports as a percentage of GDP) rose from 28 to

around 60 percent, incoming foreign direct investment jumped

from $28 to $92 billion, and China emerged as a substantial

source of outbound direct investment, with annual flows

rising from $4.4 billion in 1993 to $52.1 billion in

2008.[25]



These important structural changes occurred amid a further

acceleration of growth that has pushed the leading edge of

urban prosperity into new territory, with affluent

households now able to afford luxury housing, private

automobiles, international travel, and overseas schooling

for their children. Strong momentum has enabled China's

economy to power through sharp setbacks from the

international financial crises of 1998 and 2008/09 as well

as the 2003 SARS epidemic.[26]



REFORM SUCCESS

One vital ingredient in China's long-term reform success

came from domestic policies that pushed aside major

obstacles to improved economic performance by improving

incentives and allowing increased entry, competition,

mobility, and price flexibility. Although these reforms

remain incomplete-private businesses, for example, still

confront formidable legal, administrative, and institutional

barriers-they created sufficient momentum to overcome the

friction and drag linked to a host of less critical

inefficiencies associated with price distortions, imperfect

markets, and institutional shortcomings (for example in

banking, property rights, and corporate governance)-all of

which retarded growth and increased its cost without

endangering the ongoing boom.



The combination of Chinese land and labor with the capital

and expertise of Taiwan and Hong Kong industrialists

provided a particularly important boost to exports and

employment during the first decade of reform. China's

coastal regions used the experience and confidence gained

from initial cooperation with Overseas Chinese entrepreneurs

to attract rising investment flows from multi-national

corporations. Foreign investment has powered China's revival

as a great trading nation and contributed to the expansion

of Chinese manufacturing capability (for example, in

automobiles).



CHINA'S FUTURE

What of the future? China's economic prospects appear

strong. Rapid diffusion of education will further improve

its already impressive pool of human resources.

Entrepreneurship flourishes despite remaining barriers to

the expansion of private business. With public interest in

socialist ideology notably absent, China's political elites

understand that continued economic growth is essential to

maintaining their own power; their focus on development is

therefore intense. Manufacturing, the largest and strongest

sector of China's economy, seems poised for further

upgrading, which will benefit from enlarged flows of college

graduates, domestic R&D activity, and new ideas from China's

growing portfolio of international investments.



China's efforts to harvest these promising economic

opportunities must confront formidable obstacles. Although

international media and NGOs tend to exaggerate the dangers

arising from environmental and public health hazards as well

as tensions linked to ethnic and economic inequalities,

these issues pose major challenges, as do corruption and the

intertwined problems of unemployment and (especially rural)

education. The biggest dangers, however, lie elsewhere.



On the domestic side, a largely unreformed investment

mechanism allows government decisionmakers to channel funds

from state-owned banks into state-controlled investment

projects. This relic of Soviet-style planning holds back the

growth of output, productivity, and (especially) employment,

extends a long-standing pattern of grotesque seasonal

fluctuations, creates mountains of bad loans that increase

the risk of financial instability, and truncates expansion

prospects for private businesses (which find themselves

crowded out of financial markets).



On the international side, global market access, which has

made China the greatest beneficiary of globalization,

remains essential to China's future prospects. The recent

economic crisis shows how quickly disruption of overseas

export sales can undercut domestic economic activity (best

measured at the moment by electricity use) and employment

(Chinese economists reckon that the 2008 crisis caused over

40 million layoffs). Imports of energy, materials,

equipment, components, and technology are equally essential.

Chinese plans to grapple with a wide range of pressing

economic issues routinely anticipate unfettered access to

world markets for funds, expertise, and ideas as well as

commodities.



China's continuing growth spurt, now in its fourth decade,

is a major event in world history that has delivered massive

benefits to its citizens, and also to its trade and business

partners, including the United States. Chinese economic

expansion also creates conflict-in the economic sphere

alone, China has become involved in disputes over cross-

national shifts in production and employment, corporate

takeovers, trade imbalances and protection, environmental

hazards, currency valuation, intellectual property, internet

censorship, labor standards, subsidies, and many other

issues.



Beijing's intense focus on building a prosperous Chinese

future, along with China's large and growing reliance on

global markets to promote its economic objectives, tilts

China's international behavior toward cooperation rather

than conflict. Despite the inevitable friction that

accompanies the China's expanding economic, political,

military, and technological strength, this orientation,

which is evident in Beijing's approach to issues surrounding

trade, environment, property rights, and the Korean

peninsula, creates an opportunity for the international

community to adjust to China's expanding power and influence

through mutual agreement rather than armed struggle.



----------------------------------------------------------

Notes



[1] The author acknowledges beneficial advice from Lucien

Ellington and two anonymous reviewers.



[2] For example, C. Fred Bergsten et al, China's Rise:

Challenges and Opportunities (Washington: Peterson

Institute, 2008); William W. Keller and Thomas G. Rawski

eds., China's Rise and the Balance of Influence in Asia

(Pittsburgh, U. of Pittsburgh Press, 2007).



[3] Angus Maddison, The world economy: a millennial

perspective (Paris: OECD, 2001).



[4] The Travels of Marco Polo, available at

http://books.google.com/books?id=VovVAAAAMAAJ&printsec=front

cover&dq=travels+of+marco+polo#v=onepage&q=&f=false



[5] For Chinese and English versions, see

http://www.readchinese.net/chabuduoxiansheng



[6] G. W. Skinner, Chinese Society in Thailand (Ithaca:

Cornell U. Press, 1957), pp. 97, 92, 93. 95.



[7] Ibid. 102, 105.



[8] G. W. Skinner, Marketing and Social Structure in Rural

China (Ann Arbor: AAS, 1965).



[9] Evelyn S. Rawski, Education and Popular Literacy in

Ch'ing China, (Ann Arbor: U. of Michigan Press, 1979), chap.1.



[10] Joerg Baten et al, "Evolution of living standards and

human capital in China in the 18-20th centuries."

Explorations in Economic History, forthcoming.



[11] Sarasin Viraphol, Tribute and Profit: Sino-Siamese

Trade, 1652-1853 (Cambridge: Harvard Council, 1977), p. 170.



[12] For an architectural example, see

http://www.nytimes.com/2009/12/04/world/asia/04taishan.html?emc=eta1



[13] Loren Brandt and Thomas G. Rawski eds., China's Great

Economic Transformation (Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press,

2008), p. 625



[14] Gong Zhengzheng, "Central China Urged to Up Ante."

China Daily, 28 April 2008, p. 2.



[15] Carl Trocki warns that "Much of the literature [on

opium] is emotional, uninformed, highly prejudiced and

intended to persuade rather than to inform" (Opium, Empire

and the Global Political Economy (London: Routledge, 1999),

p. 177).



[16] "International Economics," in Thomas G. Rawski et al,

Economics and the Historian (Berkeley: U. of California

Press, 1996), p. 229.



[17] On coal, see Kenneth Pomeranz, The Great Divergence

(Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 2000).



[18] Thomas G. Rawski, Economic Growth in Prewar China

(Berkeley: U. of California Press, 1989), chap. 6.



[19] Ibid, chap. 3.



[20] Shu-min Huang, The Spiral Road (Boulder: Westview

Press, 1989), p. 61.



[21] Uma J. Lele, The design of rural development: lessons

from Africa (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U. Press, 1975), pp.

127, 131.



[22] China Statistical Yearbook 1991- abbreviated below as

CSY (Beijing: China Statistics Press, 1991), pp. 377, 628;

David Zweig, Internationalizing China (Ithaca: Cornell U.

Press, 2002), p. 121.



[23] Susan Shirk, The Political Logic of Economic Reform in

China (Berkeley: U. of California Press, 1993).



[24] CSY 1994, p. 373; 2009, Table 13.1.



[25] Data from CSY, 1994 and 2009; Penn World Tables; UNCTAD

website.



[26] Official data conceal the impact of these reversals on

overall output. For example, official reports for the

fourth quarter of 2008 show electricity output falling by

12.1 percent compared to year-earlier results, but claim

that GDP expanded by 6.8 percent during the same period.



----------------------------------------------------------

Copyright Foreign Policy Research Institute

(http://www.fpri.org/).

No comments:

Post a Comment